Public Consultation: Revision of the EU’s electricity market design

Renewables Norway (13.02.2023)

Background

Over the last year, electricity prices have been significantly higher than before. Prices started rising rapidly in summer of 2021 when Russia reduced its gas supplies to Europe while global demand picked up as COVID-19 restrictions were eased. Subsequently, Russia’s invasion of Ukraine and its weaponisation of energy sources have led to substantially lower levels of gas delivery to the EU and increased disruptions of gas supply, further driving up the price. This has had a severe impact on EU households and the economy. High gas prices influence the price of electricity from gas fired power plants, often needed to satisfy electricity demand.

In the immediate reaction to global dynamics, the EU provided an energy prices toolbox with measures to address high prices (including income support, tax breaks, gas saving and storage measures). The subsequent weaponisation of gas supply and Russia’s manipulation of the markets through intentional disruptions of gas flows have led not only to skyrocketing energy prices, but also to endangering security of supply. To address it, the EU had to act to diversify gas supplies and to accelerate energy efficiency and the deployment of renewable energy.

Following the Russian invasion of Ukraine in February 2022, the EU responded with REPowerEU - a plan for the Union to rapidly end its dependence on Russian energy supplies by strengthening the European resilience and security, reducing energy consumption, accelerating the roll-out of renewables and energy efficiency, and securing alternative energy supplies. The EU also established a temporary State Aid regime to allow certain subsidies to soften the impact of high prices. Further, to address the price crisis and security concerns, the EU has agreed and implemented a strong gas storage regime, effective demand reduction measures for gas and electricity, and price limiting regimes to avoid windfall profits in both gas
and electricity markets.

The EU Electricity Market Design

The current electricity market design has delivered a well-integrated market, allowing Europe to reap the economic benefits of a single energy market in the normal market circumstances, ensuring security of supply and sustaining the decarbonisation process. Cross-border interconnectivity also ensures safer, more reliable and efficient operation of the power system.

Market design has also helped the emergence of new and innovative products and measures on retail electricity markets – supporting energy efficiency and renewable uptake and helping consumers reduce their energy bills also through emerging services for providing demand response. Building on and seizing the potential of the digitalisation of the energy system, such as active participation by consumers, will be a key element of our future electricity markets and systems.

In the context of the energy crisis, the current electricity market design has however also demonstrated a number of shortcomings. The reforms the Commission will undertake will address those shortcomings and ensure stable and well-integrated energy markets, which continue to attract private investments at a sufficient scale as an essential enabler of the European Green Deal objectives and the transition to a climate neutral economy by 2050.

In addition to these shortcomings, the European electricity sector is facing a number of more long-term challenges triggered by the rising shares of variable renewable energy and the progressive drive towards full decarbonisation by 2050. This includes ensuring investments, not just as regards renewables but also as regards weather independent low-carbon technologies until large scale storage and other flexibility tools become available. Stronger locational price signals in the system may be needed to ensure that the investments take place where they are needed, reflecting the physical reality of the electricity grid whilst at the same time ensuring incentives for cross-border long-term contracting. Some of these challenges will
require ongoing policy reflections going beyond the scope of the current reform.

Making Electricity Bills More Independent from the Short-Term Cost of Fossil Fuels

The strong focus of the current market design on short-term markets, still very often determined by volatile fossil fuel prices, has exposed households and companies to significant price spikes with effects on their electricity bills. Many consumers found they had no option but to pay higher electricity prices driven by wholesale gas prices – either because they had no access to electricity cheaper electricity from renewable sources or could not install solar panels themselves.

The current regulatory framework regarding long-term instruments has proven insufficient to protect large industrial consumers, SMEs and households from excessive volatility and higher energy bills.

The gas price increase together with the strong role that short-term markets play in today’s electricity market design have also boosted the revenues and profits well beyond the expectations of many generators with lower marginal costs such as renewables and nuclear (“inframarginal generators”), while receiving – in some cases - public support as well.

Short-term markets remain essential for the integration of renewable energy sources in the electricity system, to ensure that the cheapest form of electricity is used at all times, and to ensure that electricity flows smoothly between Member States. Whilst short-term price spikes can in general incentivize consumers to reduce or shift their demand, sustained high prices over a longer period translate into unaffordable bills for many consumers and companies.

This is why there is a need to complement the regulatory framework governing these short-term markets with additional instruments and tools that incentivise the use of long-term contracts to ensure that the energy bills of European consumers and companies - and the revenues of inframarginal generators - become more independent from the fluctuation of prices in short-term markets (often driven by fossil fuel costs) and thus more stable over longer periods of time. The reforms should create a buffer between consumers and short-term markets, ensuring that they will be better protected from extreme prices and that
electricity bills better reflect the overall electricity mix and the lower cost of generating electricity from renewables. Electricity bills across Europe should depend less on the short-term markets, with an increasing share of consumers shifting into more stable and affordable longer-term pricing arrangements.

There are two main types of long-terms contracts which allow to pass on the benefits of renewables to all consumers. One is power purchase agreements (PPAs) between private parties which ensure that electricity is sold on a long-term basis at an agreed price, therefore not determined by short-term markets. Power purchase agreements bring multiple benefits. For consumers, they provide cost competitive electricity and hedge against electricity price volatility. For renewable projects developers, they provide a source of stable long-term income. For governments, they provide an alternative avenue to the deployment of renewables without the need for public funding. Although power purchase agreements are becoming more widespread in the EU and the Renewable Energy Directive obliges the Member States to remove unjustified barriers to their development, the overall market share of power purchase agreements remains limited. The growth of power purchase agreements is concentrated in some Member States only and confined to large companies.

The Commission will suggest ways in which the share of PPAs in the overall electricity market can be increased and their roll-out incentivised through the market design. The uptake of power purchase agreements, in particular by small and medium companies, can, for example, be more widely promoted by public tendering for renewable energy in which a share of a project could be contracted through power purchase agreements. Credit guarantees to power purchase agreements backed by public actors could be considered as a form of support that could efficiently drive the emergence of a power purchase agreement market. Potentially, measures could be considered to ensure that industrial consumers use the full potential
of power purchase agreements to lower their exposure to short-term markets and that energy suppliers more actively enter into the power purchase agreement market.

The other type of long-term contracts applies where public support is needed to trigger investments, socalled two-way contracts for difference (“two-way CfDs”). These contracts ensure that the income of the generators in question (and the corresponding cost for consumers) provides an adequate incentive to invest and is less dependent on short-term markets. These contracts for difference are typically established by a competitive tender process, allowing support to be channelled to the projects with the lowest expected
production costs. In situations of very high prices two-way CfDs would provide Member States with additional funds for reducing the impact of high electricity prices on consumers.

The upcoming reform offers an opportunity to present ways in which two-way CfDs can be integrated into the electricity market design. A number of issues need to be considered in this context, notably as to the extent to which the use of CfDs becomes mandatory for investments involving public support and whether the use of such contracts should only cover new generation assets entering the market or also certain types of existing generation assets.
In any case, given the multiple benefits of the power purchase agreements, the actions of the reform concerning the CfDs should not affect the development of the power purchase agreement market across the EU. Both instruments are necessary complements to achieve the necessary deployment of renewables.

  • The simplest way to introduce two-way CfDs would be to complement the existing principles for support schemes with the specific ones to govern such contracts in the regulatory framework, with Member States deciding whether or not to use these instruments to drive new investments in inframarginal generation.
  • A more binding way to anchor these contracts in the regulatory framework would be to require that all investments involving the use of public support rely on such contract structures. This would need to be carefully calibrated to ensure that CfDs provide the necessary incentives at the least cost for consumers.
  • Another option would be to not only envisage the use of CfDs for new generation but also to allow Member States to offer contracts on certain types of existing inframarginal generators (e.g., for specific types of technologies). These contracts could be awarded to existing generation, where possible, on the basis of competitive bidding.
  • A more far-reaching approach would be to not only envisage the use of CfDs for new generation but also to allow Member States to impose these contracts on certain types of existing inframarginal generators (e.g., for specific types of technologies). Contrary to the situation for new generation, the contracts for these types of existing generators would typically not result from market-based tendering but would result from ex-post price regulation. Whilst this would accelerate the uptake of contracts for difference, it would also create significant uncertainty for investors in renewables. This could risk the necessary investments in this type of generation, increase the costs of those investments and as a result be counterproductive.
Driving Renewable Investments – Europe’s Way Out of the Crisis

Increasing renewable energy deployment as well as electrification in general, is critical for Europe’s security of supply, the affordability of energy and achieving climate neutrality by 2050. The accelerated deployment of renewables and energy efficiency measures will structurally reduce demand for fossil fuels in the power, heating and cooling, industry and transport sectors. Thanks to their low operational costs, renewables can lower energy prices across the EU. Furthermore, faster deployment of renewable energy will contribute to EU’s security of energy supply.

Any regulatory intervention in the electricity market design therefore needs to preserve and enhance the incentives for investments and provide investors with certainty and predictability, while addressing the economic and social concerns related to high energy prices.

Alternatives to Gas to Keep the Electricity System in Balance

The consultation also covers ways to improve the conditions under which flexibility solutions such as demand response, energy storage and other weather independent renewable and low carbon sources, compete in the markets. These include measures aimed at incentivising the development of such flexibility solutions in the market (such as adapting the tariff design of system operators to ensure that they fully consider all flexibility solutions and use the existing network as efficiently as possible, allowing for access to more detailed data from electricity consumers through the installation of submeters or developing products to reduce demand or shift energy consumption in periods of high demand or prices) and targeted measures
to improve the efficiency of the short-term markets, with particular focus on the intraday market (such as allowing trading across Member States closer to the delivery of electricity and further increasing the liquidity in this market). In addition, the consultation seeks input on how to safeguard security of supply and adequacy also in situations of unforeseen crisis to ensure timely investments in capacity.

Combined with renewable generation and enhanced investments in grid capacity and inter-connectivity, this should contribute to reducing the role that natural gas-fired generation plays as a flexible source of generation and will, over time, replace, and thereby, phase out natural gas-fired power generation in line with the EU’s decarbonisation targets.

Lessons Learned from Short Term Market Interventions

During the crisis, a number of emergency and temporary market interventions have been introduced to mitigate the impact of high energy prices on consumers and companies. In the electricity market, the measure introduced at EU level is the so-called inframarginal cap, which softened the impact of high prices whilst requiring mandatory demand reduction.

The consultation seeks stakeholders’ views on whether certain aspects of these emergency interventions could be turned into more structural features of the electricity market design, for example activated in future crisis situations, and if so, under what conditions.

Any such potential element of the reform would depend on the success of these measures in terms of limiting the impact of high electricity prices and on whether they can be introduced without harming the investment incentives required to achieve the decarbonisation of the power sector.

Better Consumer Empowerment and Protection

The energy crisis has exposed consumers across the internal market to higher energy costs – resulting in a real lowering of their standard of living. In some cases, customers face a choice between paying for their energy and buying other essential goods[1][2]. The crisis has also hit industry and service sectors increasing energy costs, particularly for energy intensive industry. This has given rise to cuts in production capacity, temporarily or permanent closures and lay-offs.

The Electricity Directive has not yet been fully implemented. Better implementation, and enforcement of consumer rights, would have helped mitigate the impact of the crisis for consumers. However, targeted improvements are also needed. This consultation covers different options for creating a buffer between consumers and short-term energy markets.

By giving consumers who want to actively participate in energy markets more opportunities do so, including by sharing energy to control their costs[3]. We can also better use digitalisation tools to make it easier for consumers with renewable heating or electromobility to manage their costs through avoiding the most expensive times of the day to use grid electricity. Even without being active on the market consumers need to be able to access longer term contracts for electricity, notably based on renewable power purchase agreements between suppliers and renewable producers. This will allow them to manage their costs and support new investments in renewable energy.

The crisis has also shown that often consumers pick up the costs when suppliers fail. This could be mitigated by requiring suppliers to be adequately hedged, combined with an effective Supplier of Last Resort Regime to ensure continuity of supply.

Finally, in cases of crisis it may be worthwhile enabling Member States to guarantee households and SMEs access to a minimum necessary amount of electricity at an affordable price, as was done in the Council Regulation (EU) 2022/1854 of 6 October 2022 on an emergency intervention to address high energy prices.

Stronger Protection against Market Manipulation

Regulation 1227/2011 on wholesale market integrity and transparency (REMIT) ensures that consumers and other market participants can have confidence in the integrity of electricity and natural gas markets, that prices reflect a fair and competitive interplay between supply and demand, and that no profits can be drawn from market abuse. In times of very high price volatility, external actors’ interference, reduced supplies, and new trading behaviours, there is a risk that entities engage in illegal wholesale trading practices. There is therefore a need to ensure that the REMIT framework is up to date and robust. Further improvements would increase transparency, monitoring capacities and ensure more effective investigation
and enforcement of cross-border cases in the EU to support new electricity market design.

Next Steps

The aim of the present public consultation is to give the opportunity to all stakeholders and other interested parties to provide feedback on a series of policy objectives to be pursued by the reform proposal and possible concrete legislative and non-legislative measures resulting from them.

The Commission intends to present a proposal for amendments to the electricity market design in March 2023. The replies to the present consultation should be provided by 13 February 2023 at the latest.

Profilbilde av